
Traveler's Dilemma
The traveler's dilemma, in game theory, is a non-zero-sum game in which two players attempt to maximize their own payoff, without regard for the other. According to game theory, the rational strategy for both players is to choose the lowest possible payoff which results in both players receiving lower payoffs than they could achieve by following an irrational strategy. However, traveler’s dilemma studies have also shown that when the penalty/bonus is larger or when the players consist of teams of several people who make a common decision, then the players more often choose to follow the rational strategy that leads to the Nash equilibrium. In experimental studies, people consistently chose higher payoffs and achieved better results than the rational strategy predicted by game theory. In experimental studies, contrary to the predictions of game theory, most people pick $100 or a number close to it, either without thinking the problem through or while fully aware they are deviating from the rational choice.

More in Economy
What Is the Traveler's Dilemma?
The traveler's dilemma, in game theory, is a non-zero-sum game in which two players attempt to maximize their own payoff, without regard for the other. The game demonstrates the "paradox of rationality" — the irony that making decisions illogically or naively often produces a better payoff in game theory.



Understanding the Traveler's Dilemma
The traveler’s dilemma game, formulated in 1994 by economist Kaushik Basu, presents a scenario in which an airline severely damages identical antiques purchased by two different travelers. Management is willing to compensate them for the loss of the antiques, but since they have no idea about their value, they tell the two travelers to separately write down their estimate of the value as any number between $2 and $100 without conferring with one another.
However, there are a couple of caveats:
- If both travelers write down the same number, they will be reimbursed that amount.
- If they write different numbers, management will assume that the lower price is the actual value and that the person with the higher number is cheating. While they will pay both of them the lower figure, the person with the lower number will get a $2 bonus for honesty, while the one who wrote the higher number will get a $2 penalty.
The rational choice, in terms of the Nash equilibrium, is $2. The reasoning goes as follows.
Choosing Nash Equilibrium
In experimental studies, contrary to the predictions of game theory, most people pick $100 or a number close to it, either without thinking the problem through or while fully aware they are deviating from the rational choice. So, while most people intuitively feel that they would select a much higher number than $2, this intuition seems to contradict the logical outcome predicted by game theory — that each traveler would select $2. By rejecting the logical choice and acting illogically by writing a higher number, people end up getting a substantially bigger payoff.
These results agree with similar studies using other games such as the Prisoner’s Dilemma and the Public Goods game, where experimental subjects tend not to choose the Nash equilibrium. Based on these studies, researchers have proposed that people appear to have a natural, positive attitude in favor of cooperation. This attitude leads to cooperative equilibria that provide higher payoffs to all players in single-shot or repeated games and can be explained by selective evolutionary pressures that favor these kinds of seemingly irrational but beneficial strategies.
However, traveler’s dilemma studies have also shown that when the penalty/bonus is larger or when the players consist of teams of several people who make a common decision, then the players more often choose to follow the rational strategy that leads to the Nash equilibrium. These effects also interact, in that teams of players not only choose the more rational strategy but are also even more responsive to the size of the penalty/bonus than individual players.
These studies suggest that evolved strategies that tend to create beneficial social outcomes can be offset by more rational strategies that tend toward the Nash equilibrium depending on the structure of the incentives and the presence of social divisions.
Related terms:
Backward Induction
In game theory, backward induction is the process of deducing backward from the end of a problem or scenario to infer a sequence of optimal actions. read more
Centipede Game
The centipede game in game theory involves two players alternately getting a chance to take the larger share of an increasing money stash. read more
Dollar Auction
A dollar auction is a non-zero-sum sequential game where the highest bidder receives a dollar and the loser must pay the amount that they bid as well. read more
Economics : Overview, Types, & Indicators
Economics is a branch of social science focused on the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. read more
Game Theory
Game theory is a framework for modeling scenarios in which conflicts of interest exist among the players. read more
Inflation
Inflation is a decrease in the purchasing power of money, reflected in a general increase in the prices of goods and services in an economy. read more
Nash Equilibrium
The Nash Equilibrium is a game theory concept where the optimal outcome is when there is no incentive for players to deviate from their initial strategy. read more
Paradox of Rationality
The paradox of rationality is the empirical observation that players who make irrational choices often receive better payoffs than those making rational choices. read more
Prisoner's Dilemma
The prisoner's dilemma is a paradox in decision analysis in which two individuals acting in their own self-interests do not produce the optimal outcome. read more
Public Good
A public good is a product that one individual can consume without reducing its availability to others and from which no one is excluded. read more