
Paradox of Rationality
The paradox of rationality is the observation, in game theory and experimental economics, that players who make irrational or naive choices often receive better payoffs and that those making the rational choices predicted by backward induction often receive worse outcomes. The paradox of rationality is consistently observed in experimental studies of game theory using such well-known games as the prisoner’s dilemma, the traveler’s dilemma, the diner’s dilemma, the public good game, and the centipede game — and underscores the contradictions between intuition and reasoning and between the predictions of rational choice theory and actual behavior. Such seemingly irrational behavior can lead to results that cannot be explained by theories that solely rely on individual rational choice. The rational choice in a context-free game theoretic setting might be very different from the rational choice that a real individual accustomed to a certain set of formal and informal institutional rules and norms of behavior will make. The paradox of rationality is the observation, in game theory and experimental economics, that players who make irrational or naive choices often receive better payoffs and that those making the rational choices predicted by backward induction often receive worse outcomes. Economists have developed several strands of research that can help explain how and why behavior differs from the perfect rationality of game theory, including behavioral economics, new institutional economics, and evolutionary economics.

More in Economy
What Is the Paradox of Rationality?
The paradox of rationality is the observation, in game theory and experimental economics, that players who make irrational or naive choices often receive better payoffs and that those making the rational choices predicted by backward induction often receive worse outcomes. A paradox of rationality appears to show that there are benefits to irrationality or at least to seemingly irrational behavior. It is common to games that have Nash equilibria, which produce overall outcomes that leave the players worse off than they could have been had they chosen less rational individual strategies. When the players do not reach the expected equilibrium solution it suggests that something more than purely rational individual choice is at work.



Understanding the Paradox of Rationality
The paradox of rationality is consistently observed in experimental studies of game theory using such well-known games as the prisoner’s dilemma, the traveler’s dilemma, the diner’s dilemma, the public good game, and the centipede game — and underscores the contradictions between intuition and reasoning and between the predictions of rational choice theory and actual behavior.
Such seemingly irrational behavior can lead to results that cannot be explained by theories that solely rely on individual rational choice. That people do not always behave rationally is a challenge to traditional economic and financial theories, which assume individual rationality. For example, the theory of public goods, which justifies much of public policy, predicts that individuals will rationally consume as much of any available public good as they can but that none will pay for it or produce it. Yet experiments (and real world experience) show that this is often not the case.
Attempts to explain these results follow two major approaches. Some see them as a challenge to the rationality of individual choice and argue that cognitive biases must be at play in inducing people to choose irrationally. Others modify the individuality of rational choice in a social context and argue that formal and informal social institutions mediate individual choice.
Behavioral Economics
Behavioral economics explicitly considers psychological factors in individual decisions. Various cognitive biases, emotional states, or simple faulty reasoning are the root cause of observed behavior that varies from the game theoretic rational choice. Subjects either lack the rational capacity to arrive at the equilibrium strategy or are guided by unconscious biases that originate from non-rational mental processes, emotions, or habits of behavior. In some cases, new models that adapt traditional game theory logic to reflect these kind of decision maker preferences have been developed.
New Institutional Economics
New institutional economics suggests that social influences on individual economic choice are nearly ubiquitous. With the exception of a castaway on a deserted island, economic decisions routinely occur within the context of multiple layers of collective economic organizations and institutions, including households, families, business firms, clubs, and polities.
The rational choice in a context-free game theoretic setting might be very different from the rational choice that a real individual accustomed to a certain set of formal and informal institutional rules and norms of behavior will make. Consideration of the individual’s specific institutional setting introduces a kind of meta-rationality that is oriented, either by design or by spontaneous order, toward achieving more beneficial outcomes for all members of the group. Experimental subjects inevitably bring this “baggage” with them when they participate in games, and choose strategies that reflect the institutional arrangements that they understand and are conditioned to follow.
Evolutionary Economics
Evolutionary economics bridges the gap between these fields in that it draws on evolutionary biology and evolutionary psychology to explain deviations from individual rational choice. According to evolutionary economics, individuals exhibit the cognitive biases described by behavioral economics and develop the formal and informal frameworks studied by New Institutional economics because of selective evolutionary pressures that produce an adaptive response. Cognitive biases and economic institutions that explain paradoxes of rationality are group evolutionary strategies that can be adapted specifically for overcoming those individually rational game theoretic equilibria that are harmful to the group.
Related terms:
Backward Induction
In game theory, backward induction is the process of deducing backward from the end of a problem or scenario to infer a sequence of optimal actions. read more
Behavioral Economics
Behavioral Economics is the study of psychology as it relates to the economic decision-making processes of individuals and institutions. read more
Centipede Game
The centipede game in game theory involves two players alternately getting a chance to take the larger share of an increasing money stash. read more
Diner's Dilemma
Diner's dilemma is a situation where several people agree to split the bill before going out to eat and order higher-priced items than they normally would. read more
Economics : Overview, Types, & Indicators
Economics is a branch of social science focused on the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. read more
Evolutionary Economics
Evolutionary economics proposes that economic processes evolve and are determined both by individuals and society as a whole. read more
Experimental Economics
Experimental economics studies human behavior in a controlled setting, to test economic theories by seeing how people respond to incentives. read more
Game Theory
Game theory is a framework for modeling scenarios in which conflicts of interest exist among the players. read more
Inflation
Inflation is a decrease in the purchasing power of money, reflected in a general increase in the prices of goods and services in an economy. read more
Nash Equilibrium
The Nash Equilibrium is a game theory concept where the optimal outcome is when there is no incentive for players to deviate from their initial strategy. read more