
Marginal Utility
Marginal utility is the added satisfaction that a consumer gets from having one more unit of a good or service. Positive marginal utility occurs when the consumption of an additional item increases the total utility. The concept of marginal utility was developed by economists who were attempting to explain the economic reality of price, which they believed was driven by a product's utility. On the other hand, negative marginal utility occurs when the consumption of one more unit decreases the overall utility. In general, people will continue consuming more of a good as long as the marginal utility is greater than the marginal cost.

More in Economy
What Is Marginal Utility?
Marginal utility is the added satisfaction that a consumer gets from having one more unit of a good or service. The concept of marginal utility is used by economists to determine how much of an item consumers are willing to purchase.
Positive marginal utility occurs when the consumption of an additional item increases the total utility. On the other hand, negative marginal utility occurs when the consumption of one more unit decreases the overall utility.




Understanding Marginal Utility
Economists use the idea of marginal utility to gauge how satisfaction levels affect consumer decisions. Economists have also identified a concept known as the law of diminishing marginal utility. It describes how the first unit of consumption of a good or service carries more utility than later units.
Although marginal utility tends to decrease with consumption, it may or may not ever reach zero depending on the good consumed.
Marginal utility is useful in explaining how consumers make choices to get the most benefit from their limited budgets. In general, people will continue consuming more of a good as long as the marginal utility is greater than the marginal cost. In an efficient market, the price equals the marginal cost. That is why people keep buying more until the marginal utility of consumption falls to the price of the good.
The law of diminishing marginal utility is often used to justify progressive taxes. The idea is that higher taxes cause less loss of utility for someone with a higher income. In this case, everyone gets diminishing marginal utility from money. Suppose that the government must raise $20,000 from each person to pay for its expenses. If the average income is $60,000 before taxes, then the average person would make $40,000 after taxes and have a reasonable standard of living.
However, asking people making only $20,000 to give it all up to the government would be unfair and demand a far greater sacrifice. That is why poll taxes, which require everyone to pay an equal amount, tend to be unpopular.
Also, a flat tax without individual exemptions that required everyone to pay the same percentage would impact those with less income more because of marginal utility. Someone making $15,000 per year would be taxed into poverty by a 33% tax, while someone making $60,000 would still have about $40,000.
Types of Marginal Utility
There are multiple kinds of marginal utility. Three of the most common ones are as follows:
Positive Marginal Utility
Positive marginal utility occurs when having more of an item brings additional happiness. Suppose you like eating a slice of cake, but a second slice would bring you some extra joy. Then, your marginal utility from consuming cake is positive.
Zero Marginal Utility
Zero marginal utility is what happens when consuming more of an item brings no extra measure of satisfaction. For example, you might feel fairly full after two slices of cake and wouldn't really feel any better after having a third slice. In this case, your marginal utility from eating cake is zero.
Negative Marginal Utility
Negative marginal utility is where you have too much of an item, so consuming more is actually harmful. For instance, the fourth slice of cake might even make you sick after eating three pieces of cake.
History of Marginal Utility
The concept of marginal utility was developed by economists who were attempting to explain the economic reality of price, which they believed was driven by a product's utility. In the 18th century, economist Adam Smith discussed what is known as "the paradox of water and diamonds." This paradox states that water has far less value than diamonds, even though water is vital to human life.
This disparity intrigued economists and philosophers around the world. In the 1870s, three economists — William Stanley Jevons, Carl Menger, and Leon Walras — each independently came to the conclusion that marginal utility was the answer to the water and diamonds paradox. In his book, The Theory of Political Economy, Jevons explained that economic decisions are made based on "final" (marginal) utility rather than total utility.
Example of Marginal Utility
David has four gallons of milk, then decides to purchase a fifth gallon. Meanwhile, Kevin has six gallons of milk and likewise chooses to buy an additional gallon. David benefits from not having to go to the store again for a few days, so his marginal utility is still positive. On the other hand, Kevin may have purchased more milk than he can reasonably consume, meaning his marginal utility might be zero.
The chief takeaway from this scenario is that the marginal utility of a buyer who acquires more and more of a product steadily declines. Eventually, there is no additional consumer need for the product in many cases. At that point, the marginal utility of the next unit equals zero and consumption ends.
Related terms:
Comparative Advantage
Comparative advantage is an economy's ability to produce a particular good or service at a lower opportunity cost than its trading partners. read more
Consumer Surplus
A consumer surplus occurs when the price that consumers pay for a product or service is less than the price they're willing to pay. read more
Demand Curve
The demand curve is a representation of the correlation between the price of a good or service and the amount demanded for a period of time. read more
Demand
Demand is an economic principle that describes consumer willingness to pay a price for a good or service. read more
Economic Equilibrium
Economic equilibrium is a condition or state in which economic forces are balanced. read more
Elasticity & Explanation
Elasticity is an economic term describing the change in the behavior of buyers and sellers in response to a price change for a good or service. read more
Expected Utility
Expected utility is an economic term summarizing the utility that an entity or aggregate economy is expected to reach under any number of circumstances. read more
Flat
A flat tax system applies the same tax rate to every taxpayer regardless of their income bracket. Discover more about the flat tax system here. read more
Federal Poverty Level (FPL)
The federal poverty level (FPL) is an economic measure used to decide whether an individual or family qualifies for certain federal benefits and programs. read more
Income Effect
Income effect is the change in demand for a good or service caused by a change in a consumer's purchasing power due to a change in real income. read more